by Jeff Sovern
Story here. The joke is courtesy of my brother-in-law, Ray Conley.
by Jeff Sovern
Story here. The joke is courtesy of my brother-in-law, Ray Conley.
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Friday, January 07, 2022 at 11:04 AM in Advertising, Unfair & Deceptive Acts & Practices (UDAP) | Permalink | Comments (0)
Recently, the blog posted two items (here and here) arguing that the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau should issue a rule barring the use of arbitration clauses unless consumers opt in to them. The second item was in reply to Mark Levin's blog post at Ballard Spahr's Consumer Finance Monitor blog response to our first blog post. Mark Budnitz, Georgia State Professor of Law Emeritus, has contributed the following guest post to the debate:
Opt-in is the only fair method of obtaining a consumer’s consent in pre-dispute arbitration agreements: It is impossible for consumers to make a knowing and intelligent pre-dispute waiver of their right to a judicial forum except in rare circumstances. That rare situation is where the consumer knows for a certainty what type or types of disputes they may have with the company, and there is no way arbitration is not the superior route to take.
Otherwise, the consumer cannot know, pre-dispute, which forum is better.
Discovery is one example. Does the dispute depend on documents within the sole possession of the company? If so, the limited discovery in arbitration should be avoided. Would it help the consumer prove their case to be able to make motions to produce documents, submit interrogatories, take depositions? There’s no way to know pre-dispute.
Will the company be suing the consumer, or will the consumer be suing the company? Will both have claims against the other? If the consumer may be the plaintiff or have a counterclaim, does the consumer have a sound legal argument for punitive damages? Does the arbitrator have the authority under the arbitration service rules or case law to award them? There’s no way to know pre-dispute if punitives are even an issue.
Does the consumer need a lawyer? She may not be able to retain one unless she has a claim against the company and can get into court and file a class action. Most consumer disputes do not involve enough money for it to be worthwhile for consumers to hire a lawyer whether they are the plaintiff or the defendant.
Pre-dispute, it is impossible for the consumer to know if she will have a dispute that can be brought and awarded satisfactory damages in small claims court. I know that some companies give consumers the option of arbitration or filing in small claims court. But if the consumer has a claim for substantial damages, she will not be able to recover what she is entitled to in small claims court. In addition, it is reasonable to assume many agreements do not provide that choice.
Which route will be less expensive for the consumer? Does the agreement require a panel of three arbitrators, all of which charge by the hour with the costs split between the parties? The answer is in the rules that govern arbitration under the agreement. Often the agreement merely provides a link to the arbitration service or services and depends on the consumer to read the rules of the services. How likely is it that consumers will do that before a dispute arises; if they do, how likely is it they will understand the full significance of the provisions?
Arguably AAA and JAMS are reputable and fair within the constraints of their rules. However, in doing research for an article years ago, I found arbitration agreements specifying that AAA’s Commercial Rules would apply, not its Consumer Rules. Some agreements just provided that AAA’s rules apply and did not specify which rules.
We should not forget that there are other arbitration services besides AAA and JAMS, and they may be of questionable legitimacy. Remember NAF? They were the darling of industry and often the sole arbitration service allowed under arbitration agreements. NAF was so corrupt that they completely shut down their consumer arbitrations within a week of being sued by the Minnesota A.G. for its illegal operations. Swanson v. Nat’l Arbitration Forum, (Minn. Dist. Ct., July 14, 2009). I don’t know what the situation is now, but for many years in Georgia the builders of all new homes required consent to pre-dispute consumer arbitration agreements. The arbitrations were administered by a service that was controlled by the builders, and in which consumers rarely won.
And of course, the arbitration services are not subject to any specific regulations governing their rules and can change their rules and procedures at any time without first obtaining approval from any government body.
Arbitration is private. After a dispute arises, the consumer may want the dispute to be public; she may want a public airing of her grievances in court. She may hope that, even if she loses her case, other consumers will learn of her dispute and take action if they have similar experiences. With today’s social media and some disputes going viral, consumers have more opportunities to make their grievances public. A company’s reputation is often its most precious asset. Pre-dispute, the consumer has no way to know if she may have a dispute that she wants to make public.
A favorable arbitration award has no precedential effect. A consumer may believe, after a dispute arises and consulting with her lawyer, that she has a strong case that would make an important precedent benefiting thousands of consumers if it were adjudicated in court.
Levin argues that agreeing post-dispute “would severely curtail consumer arbitration [because]…one side or the other, or both inevitably use the in terrorem ‘threat’ of expensive and prolonged litigation as a negotiating tool.” Levin assumes consumers can obtain legal representation. Consumers cannot make this threat persuasively if they don’t have a lawyer, but most don’t because unless the dispute involves a substantial amount of money, hiring a lawyer does not make financial sense.
It is interesting and revealing that Levin admits companies engage in this threat. Unlike consumers, when a company makes the threat, it really has an in terrorem effect because the company has a lawyer so the threat can be carried out. And the company has the resources to make the threat a realistic possibility, unlike most consumers.
Many years ago when I used to debate with industry lawyers at PLI and ABA conferences, they would argue that arbitration was much better for consumers than going to court because of supposedly lower cost, quicker resolution, etc. I countered that if it’s so wonderful, companies could easily convince consumers, post-dispute, to agree to arbitration. Whereupon the industry lawyers would immediately acknowledge that consumers would always choose court over arbitration if given the choice post-dispute.
For all of these reasons and probably many more, there’s no way for consumers to intelligently and knowledgeably decide, pre-dispute, if they should agree to arbitration. Therefore, opt-in is the only fair method to provide consumers in pre-dispute agreements.
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Sunday, June 06, 2021 at 07:53 PM in Advertising | Permalink | Comments (0)
Here. (H/T: Matt Bruckner).
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Sunday, January 03, 2021 at 10:02 AM in Advertising, Unfair & Deceptive Acts & Practices (UDAP) | Permalink | Comments (0)
Gerrit De Geest of Washington University in St. Louis has written Rents: How Marketing Causes Inequality. Chapter One is available here. Here is the abstract:
This working paper contains the introduction and first chapter of a forthcoming book on the relationship between marketing and inequality. I argue that the dramatic rise of income inequality since 1970 has largely been caused by advances in marketing. Marketers have become better at creating and exploiting market distortions in legal ways. The legal system, in principle, prevents the deliberate creation of market failures, but it has not evolved at the same speed. Business schools have outsmarted law schools. This chapter offers an introduction to a new, general theory of marketing. Although marketing is meant to improve markets by bringing products to the right customers, it often does the opposite—creating “value” to businesses by making prices less transparent, splitting informed and uninformed consumers, making products incomparable, locking in consumers, exploiting psychological biases, creating network externality effects, or preventing price wars. Over the time span 1970–2015, the impact of marketing on the economy has steadily increased. Few markets have not been turned into less competitive ones by marketers, trained at modern business schools. This has significantly increased the amount of artificial profits (“rents”) in the economy.
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Tuesday, August 14, 2018 at 09:08 AM in Advertising, Consumer Law Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0)
Tamara R. Piety of Tulsa has written Advertising as Experimentation on Human Subjects. Here's the abstract:
Within the industry, it is an article of faith that consumers distrust advertising. One reason for that distrust may be that they fear being manipulated. Yet the debate about advertising and manipulation always seems to revolve around how much manipulation is really going on and whether consumer skepticism ensures that manipulation tactics will likely fail. But consumer skepticism is a flimsy defense in the face of decades of research, ever more sophisticated tactics of persuasion, billions of dollars spent, and data mining capabilities that permit increasingly detailed and granular analysis. The persuasion industry’s tactics are tested in the field, by trial and error. If a tactic works, we get more of it. In this practice we are all the guinea pigs. In a university setting, research on human subjects must be approved by an Institutional Review Board (IRB). The IRB process is supposed to ensure that research subjects’ participation is voluntary and informed, and that the potential benefits of the research outweigh the potential harms. Yet there is no IRB for our present-day marketing environment. What if it is bad for our health? More ominously still in light of recent events, what if it is bad for democracy?
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Sunday, August 05, 2018 at 11:43 AM in Advertising, Consumer Law Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (1)
Chen He of the Tilburg Law and Economics Center and Tobias J. Klein of the Tilburg University Department of Econometrics & Operations Research, Center for Economic Research, Law and Economics Center; IZA Institute of Labor Economics; and Netspar, have written Advertising as a Reminder: Evidence from the Dutch State Lottery. Here is the abstract:
We use high frequency data on TV and radio advertising together with data on online sales for lottery tickets to measure the short run effects of advertising. We find them to be strong and to last for up to about 4 hours. They are the bigger the less time there is until the draw. We develop the argument that this finding is consistent with the idea that advertisements remind consumers to buy a ticket and that consumers value this. Then, we point out that in terms of timing the interests of the firm and the consumers are aligned: consumers wish to be reminded in a way that makes them most likely to consider buying a lottery ticket. We present direct evidence that this does not only affect the timing of purchases, but leads to market expansion. Then, we develop a tractable dynamic structural model of consumer behavior, estimate the parameters of this model and simulate the effects of a number of counterfactual dynamic advertising strategies. We find that relative to the actual schedule it would be valued by the consumers and profitable for the firm to spread advertising less over time and move it to the last days before the draw.
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Thursday, May 31, 2018 at 12:55 PM in Advertising, Consumer Law Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0)
by Jeff Sovern
On April 18, the Senate Commerce Committee held a hearing on Robocalls. Among the witnesses was Adrian Abramovich, against whom the FCC has filed a forfeiture proceeding in which it seeks a penalty of $120 million. Abramavich, who testified under subpoena, commented that when he receives robocalls, he declines them or doesn't answer the phone. The FCC accuses Abramovich of scamming people, but according to the testimony of NCLC's Margot Freeman Saunders, only two of the top twenty robocallers were considered scammers, based on YouMail's Robocall Index. The leader was Capitol One, Wells Fargo was third on the list, and other well-known financial institutions and debt collectors also appeared. Law360 has more here, but it may be behind a paywall.
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Tuesday, May 01, 2018 at 03:07 PM in Advertising, Consumer Legislative Policy | Permalink | Comments (0)
Belinda Reeveand Roger Magnusson, both of The University of Sydney Law School have written Regulation of Food Advertising to Children in Six Jurisdictions: A Framework for Analyzing and Improving the Performance of Regulatory Instruments, 35 Arizona Journal of International and Comparative Law (2018). Here is the abstract:
Childhood obesity is a public health crisis, and globally, at least 170 million young people are overweight or obese. Research identifies food marketing as a key risk factor for childhood weight gain, yet there is significant debate over how food marketing to children should be regulated. This paper analyzes regulatory controls on food marketing in six jurisdictions—the United States, United Kingdom, Australia, Ireland, Canada, and Quebec— with the aim of evaluating whether regulation in each jurisdiction exhibits the features of an effective, transparent, and accountable regulatory regime. These jurisdictions use different forms of regulation to restrict food marketing to children (e.g. self-regulation, co-regulation and statutory regulation), yet research suggests that none have been entirely successful in protecting children from exposure to marketing of unhealthy food. Drawing on the disciplines of public health and regulatory studies, we present a theoretical framework for the design of effective food advertising regulation. We use this framework to evaluate the strengths and weaknesses of regulation in each jurisdiction, and to explain why both public and private regulation has been less than successful in improving the food marketing environment. Our analysis reveals significant loopholes in the substantive provisions of regulatory instruments used to restrict food marketing to children, as well as limitations in the processes of monitoring, review, and enforcement established by each scheme. Our paper concludes by pointing to ways in which food advertising regulatory schemes could be progressively strengthened, including through the use of regulatory “scaffolds” to improve the transparency, accountability and performance of regulatory instruments.
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Thursday, March 01, 2018 at 05:59 PM in Advertising, Consumer Law Scholarship | Permalink | Comments (0)
by Jeff Sovern
During the Obama administration, the Department of Education adopted a regulation obliging colleges and universities to disclose their contracts with banks governing marketing to students as well as how much the schools receive from the banks. The WSJ went through those disclosures and reported on their findings in an article, Banks Pay Big Bucks for Top Billing on College Campuses. Here's an excerpt:
The banks get to set up marketing tables at campus events, advertise their products in mailings to students and are promoted as the school’s preferred banking option.
In return, the banks pay the institutions royalties, sometimes hundreds of thousands of dollars annually and often based on the number of new accounts. Some schools also get paid each time students use their debit accounts, or earn a cut of the ATM fees. * * *
* * *
Banks and universities say the programs offer an optional convenience, allowing students to link their campus identification cards to banking services.
Consumer watchdogs say a bank’s presence on campus or co-branded marketing materials could lead students to think it is their best or even only option for banking at school.
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Tuesday, January 30, 2018 at 04:07 PM in Advertising | Permalink | Comments (0)
WaPo has a report, headlined How robo-callers outwitted the government and completely wrecked the Do Not Call list, reporting that the FTC receives 19,000 complaints per day from people on the Do-Not-Call list about robocallers. The FTC not only does not have the resources to do much about it, but when it tries, its efforts are blocked by spoofing technology. A depressing excerpt:
In the age of live telemarketing, the mere threat of prosecution or penalty was enough to deter companies with shareholders and reputations to protect. In the robo-calling epoch, dialers couldn’t care less. One, nobody knows who they are or where they’re calling from, because they all spoof their numbers. Two, more of them are doing it every year, since it’s cheap and easy to blast out automated calls from anywhere in the world. All this makes it nearly impossible to identify robo-callers, let alone penalize them. At a hearing on robo-calls in October, Sen. Susan Collins (R-Maine) said she was getting so many of them, she’d disconnected her home phone. “The list,” she said, “doesn’t work.”
* * * With an annual budget of $300 million — by contrast, the FBI’s is $9 billion — the FTC is a relatively puny federal agency. There are only 43 employees in the Division of Marketing Practices, which oversees unwanted calls. None of them . . . work full time on the issue. Ami Dziekan, who works in a different department, is the lone steward of the Do Not Call Registry. Since the robo-call ban went into effect in 2009, the FTC has brought just 33 cases against robo-callers. In those cases, defendants have been ordered to pay nearly $300 million in relief to victims, and nearly $30 million in civil penalties to the government. But even then, the FTC can’t force perpetrators to pay the fine if they argue they’re broke. Which robo-callers often seem to be. So the FTC has only collected on a fraction of those sums: $18 million in relief and less than $1 million in penalties.
Posted by Jeff Sovern on Friday, January 12, 2018 at 04:36 PM in Advertising, Federal Trade Commission | Permalink | Comments (0)